Campbell paradigm
The Campbell paradigm is a behavioral theory from social psychology. The paradigm was developed by social psychologist Florian Kaiser and his colleagues in 2010, building on an earlier suggestion by Donald T. Campbell, after whom the paradigm is named. It offers an explanation of why and when individuals engage in particular behaviors. Its main application is climate and environmental protection behavior.
Overview
The Campbell paradigm suggests that behavior is typically the result of two factors: the personal value of protecting the climate and the environment and the costs that come with a specific behavior. The paradigm stands in contrast to the widespread rational choice theories, whose prototype is the theory of planned behavior in psychology. Rational choice theories explain behavior with a behavior's expected utility.The Campbell paradigm is based on the controversial assumption that attitude and behavior are genuinely consistent. Accordingly, behavior arises spontaneously as a manifestation of a person's attitude. In contrast to Campbell's model, Kaiser and colleagues lowered their aspiration to explaining the probability of engagement only. Thus, they adopted the Rasch model as a less rigid depiction of the paradigm.
The Rasch model describes the natural logarithm of the ratio of the probability that person k will switch off the lights, and the inverse probability that person k will not switch off the lights can be regressed on person kOnly if a person’s attitude exceeds the costs of a behavior will the behavior have a reasonable chance of manifesting. This very account of why and when behavior occurs also serves as the theoretical basis for the measurement of individual attitudes.'s attitude and all the financial and figurative costs that come with switching off lights. This means more or less that k 's general attitude along with i 's specific costs determine the probability that behavior i will become manifest should the opportunity arise.
Attitude measurement
Within the Campbell paradigm, a person's attitude is derived from the behavioral costs that this person will incur to achieve the goal that is implied by the attitude. For example, the goal implied by environmental attitude is to protect the environment, whereas the goal implied by health attitude is to maintain or restore health.Behavioral costs include everything that makes behavior objectively more or less demanding: things such as effort, time, and financial costs, but also social norms and expectations, cultural practices, and the antagonistic social preferences that go hand in hand with certain behaviors. To illustrate: Someone with a pronounced preference for music by the band Rammstein will generally put forth considerable effort and spend large amounts of money to attend a concert by this band. By contrast, people with less of a preference for Rammstein’s music will attend a concert only if the ticket was a gift. And those who do not fancy Rammstein at all, expectedly, will not even listen to a song by this band when it is played on the radio.
This example shows, on the one hand, that people can engage in different things to express a more or less strongly developed preference for Rammstein’s music. On the other hand, the example also makes clear that whatever a person does to listen to Rammstein is accompanied by costs; these costs are again unique to a specific behavior. Consequently, the costs that someone bears and, thus, the behaviors that someone will engage in to attain the attitudinal goal, can be used to determine people's attitude levels. So far, several attitude scales have been developed on the basis of the Campbell paradigm: environmental attitude, attitude toward nature, attitude toward anthropogenic climate change, health attitude, attitude toward social contacts or privacy in the office, attitude toward one's own mental vigor, and attitude toward social expectations.
Behavioral explanation
In social psychology, attitudes have traditionally reflected people's motivation and, thus, their personal behavioral propensities. Analogously, what later became a measure of environmental attitude was initially introduced as a measure of people's propensity to protect the environment. This classical view of attitude as a motivation measure is of course ultimately justified only when one is able to reliably and consistently anticipate manifest behavior with an attitude measure, that is, if the notorious attitude-behavior gap does not really exist.The Campbell paradigm's explanation of behavior is extremely parsimonious as can be concluded from the Rasch model. The likelihood of engaging in a behavior is a function of two compensatory factors: a person's attitude and the sociocultural boundary conditions in which the behavior takes place. These objective conditions ultimately determine the specific costs of a behavior. Accordingly, a vegetarian lunch is not only the result of people's particular level of environmental attitude but also of the sociocultural boundary conditions in which one's lunch is chosen; for example, the promise of a financial reward makes vegetarian lunches more attractive. The question that remains is “for whom?”
The literature contains a considerable number of conjunctive behavioral explanations that speak of the cost-moderated efficacy of people's attitudes. By contrast, the Campbell Paradigm suggests that behavioral costs are unrestrictedly behaviorally effective and independent of people's attitude levels. In other words, financial rewards make vegetarian lunches more probable for everyone. This compensatory relation between behavioral costs and attitude has been repeatedly quasi-experimentally confirmed in environmental protection research.
Apparent circularity
If a person’s attitude is derived from the behaviors that the person engages in, we cannot really be surprised to subsequently find that the very same behaviors are explained by this attitude. In other words, what is the point of predicting that Peter will donate money to Greenpeace after we have already seen him donate money to Greenpeace? This apparent circularity is why, for many, including Campbell himself, explaining behavior on the basis of the Campbell paradigm seems trivial and thus pointless. However, Kaiser and colleagues have argued that any form of circularity can be comparatively easily avoided.When individual differences in people's attitude are derived from verbal behaviors expressed in questionnaires, it is by no means trivial to use the correspondingly derived attitudinal differences to predict whether people will actually eat vegetarian lunches. Circularity can thus be avoided if the indicators and the consequences of the attitude are logically and practically distinct.
In order to measure individual differences in a certain attitude, one can therefore use verbal behaviors, such as retrospective self-reports of behavior, stated intentions, appraisals, and opinions. This can be done with questionnaires. As consequences of people's attitude, one can then employ real behavior or objectively measurable traces of behavior.