Fixed book price


Fixed book price is a form of resale price maintenance applied to books. It allows publishers to determine the price of a book at which it is to be sold to the public. FBP can take the form of a law, mandatory to oblige by all retailers, or an agreement between publishers and booksellers. An example of a fixed book price law is French Lang Law, and the former Net Book Agreement in the United Kingdom is an example of a trade agreement.
The key idea of an FBP is to promote non-price competition between booksellers in order to promote the sale of little-known, difficult or otherwise culturally interesting books rather than catering only to blockbuster readers. To do so, an FBP is deemed to ensure that the booksellers that provide the corresponding presale services are able to recoup their higher costs with a guaranteed margin on blockbusters.
Fixed book price systems, with various provisos, have existed in some developed countries since the beginning of the twentieth century. They remain in force in one third member states of the European Union as well as in some other countries. Despite the name, most fixed book price laws and agreements actually set minimum prices, allowing sellers to deviate from a price set by publishers by a small degree. Thus they are only limiting price competition, not suppressing it entirely.

Principle

The main reason for introducing the FBP is conviction that a dense network of well-stocked, high quality bookshops is a necessary condition for the publication of a large variety of books, large variety itself deemed desirable for the cultural life of a country. Such bookshops have additional costs that are not borne by discounters, who just stock their shelves with the current blockbusters. Since the latter represent a large proportion of book sales, price competition between high-quality bookshops and discounters reduces bookshops' profitability.
The FBP allows the publisher to mitigate this competition and thereby guarantees a sufficient margin for high-quality bookshops to operate.

Scope

Historically, most countries with a significant book industry have known an FBPA since the 19th century. The development of competition policy in the 1970s led to a wave of repeals of those agreements at a time when any form of resale price maintenance was seen with much suspicion. Conversely, other countries enacted laws making the FBP mandatory.
The following table gives an overview of the prevalence of FBP in rich countries.
CountryFBPComment
GermanyyesSince 1888, mutual agreement replaced by law in 2002
ArgentinayesLaw since 2001
AustriayesLaw since 2000
South KoreayesLaw since 2003, amended in 2014
DenmarkyesBusiness agreement since 1837, amended in 2001
Spainyes2007 Law substituting a 1975 Law
FranceyesBusiness agreement repealed in 1979, law since 1981
GreeceyesLaw since 1997, amended in 2014
HungaryyesBusiness agreement
ItalyyesLaw since 2005
Japanyes
LuxembourgyesDomestic books only
MexicoyesLaw since 2008
NorwayyesBusiness agreement among members of book sellers association and publishers since 1962. Law binding to all book sellers proposed in 2013, but unsure whether next parliament will repeal proposal before it takes effect.
NetherlandsyesBusiness agreement since 1923, law since 2005
PortugalyesLaw since 1996
SloveniayesLaw since 2014
CroatiayesLaw since 2007
AustralianoRepealed in 1972
BelgiumyesYes, by law. The fixed price is imposed the first 6 months after publication of the book.
BrazilnoOn study
Canadano
Estoniano
United States of Americano
FinlandnoRepealed in 1971
IrelandnoThe UK Net Book Agreement applied until 1992; it was disallowed in 1994 by the Competition Authority.
Polandno
Czech Republicno
United KingdomnoRevoked in 1995
SwedennoRepealed in 1974
SwitzerlandnoProhibited by the competition authority in 1999. Legislation reintroducing it failed in a 2012 referendum.
Venezuelano

Assessment

The assessment of the FBP is a controversial one. On the one hand, most economists are skeptical of the cultural merits of the FBP and underline its distorting effect. On the other hand, other economists and the book industry argue that the FBP is the only tool that allows difficult, high-brow, and culturally significant books to be published. Therefore, they say, the distortion should account for the much larger cultural externalities of meaningful cultural works. As put it,

The cultural merits ascribed to such agreements have almost reached mythical proportions. No public debate in Europe on the cultural value of books is complete without a discussion of the FBP.

Theoretical framework

Several industrial organization frameworks can be applied to assess the consequences of the FBP.
The most commonly cited result is. This paper states that when two retailer can engage on tangible presale services, that is can undertake an unobservable costly effort that increases the demand for both of them, each one has an incentive to free-ride on the other retailer's effort by setting its price slightly below his competitor. This leads to a suboptimal level of aggregate effort. By cancelling the possibility of price competition, a FBP makes impossible this kind of opportunistic behaviour and induces both retailers to compete in services.
According to, the main idea of FBP is unconvincing for several reasons:
and provide empirical assessments of FBP comparing countries with and without a FBP. According to these authors, the two main effects of a repeal of a FBP is a displacement of small independent bookstores by larger chain outlets and a decrease in the price of bestsellers, compensated by an increase of the price of all other books.
notices that the level of book prices and the number of published titles evolves in a similar manner in all Nordic countries although only Norway has a FBP and Finland belongs to a different linguistic group. In Denmark, however, book prices have increased one-third quicker than general inflation since 1985 and the number of books sold has fallen by two-thirds, a sharp contrast with Sweden and Norway, which belong to the same linguistic group. His conclusion, supported by elements from, is that the effects of a FBP are less than both proponents and critics make them, and that other institutional agreements better explain the evolution of the book markets in those countries.
According to, the ending of the FBPA in the UK did not lead to a sharp decrease of the number of bookshops, rather to a displacement of small, independent bookshops by big-chain outlets. He notices however that the former stayed in place where a quality-sensitive demand existed, and that competition between bookshops spurred a reduction of operational costs thanks to better logistics and collection management. In a counterfactual manner, shows that in France, the FBP helped to maintain a dense network of independent bookshops, reined in the deployment of chain bookstores and spurred supermarkets to boost their offer of books. Fishwick also shows that while the number of published titles increases as fast as in France, there is no sign of an overall increase of book prices. He shows however that this stability hides a strong distributive effect. Comparison with France show that the FBP leads to an increase of the price of bestsellers relative to non-FBP markets and a decrease of low-selling or long-selling books. He argues that the assessment of this effect is difficult, since the relation between the popularity of a book and its cultural value is unclear, whereas consumers of low-selling books are, on average, wealthier than consumers of bestsellers.