Kakutani fixed-point theorem
In mathematical analysis, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem for set-valued functions. It provides sufficient conditions for a set-valued function defined on a convex, compact subset of a Euclidean space to have a fixed point, i.e. a point which is mapped to a set containing it. The Kakutani fixed point theorem is a generalization of Brouwer fixed point theorem. The Brouwer fixed point theorem is a fundamental result in topology which proves the existence of fixed points for continuous functions defined on compact, convex subsets of Euclidean spaces. Kakutani's theorem extends this to set-valued functions.
The theorem was developed by Shizuo Kakutani in 1941, and was used by John Nash in his description of Nash equilibria. It has subsequently found widespread application in game theory and economics.
Statement
Kakutani's theorem states:Definitions
;Set-valued function: A set-valued function φ from the set X to the set Y is some rule that associates one or more points in Y with each point in X. Formally it can be seen just as an ordinary function from X to the power set of Y, written as φ: X → 2Y, such that φ is non-empty for every. Some prefer the term correspondence, which is used to refer to a function that for each input may return many outputs. Thus, each element of the domain corresponds to a subset of one or more elements of the range.;Closed graph: A set-valued function φ: X → 2Y is said to have a closed graph if the set is a closed subset of X × Y in the product topology i.e. for all sequences and such that, and for all, we have.
;Fixed point: Let φ: X → 2X be a set-valued function. Then a ∈ X is a fixed point of φ if a ∈ φ.
Examples
A function with infinitely many fixed points
The function:, shown on the figure at the right, satisfies all Kakutani's conditions, and indeed it has many fixed points: any point on the 45° line which intersects the graph of the function is a fixed point, so in fact there is an infinity of fixed points in this particular case. For example, x = 0.72 is a fixed point since 0.72 ∈ .A function with a unique fixed point
The function:satisfies all Kakutani's conditions, and indeed it has a fixed point: x = 0.5 is a fixed point, since x is contained in the interval.
A function that does not satisfy convexity
The requirement that φ be convex for all x is essential for the theorem to hold.Consider the following function defined on :
The function has no fixed point. Though it satisfies all other requirements of Kakutani's theorem, its value fails to be convex at x = 0.5.
A function that does not satisfy close graph
Consider the following function defined on :The function has no fixed point. Though it satisfies all other requirements of Kakutani's theorem, its graph is not closed; for example, consider the sequences xn = 0.5 - 1/n, yn = 3/4.
Alternative statement
Some sources, including Kakutani's original paper, use the concept of upper hemicontinuity while stating the theorem:This statement of Kakutani's theorem is completely equivalent to the statement given at the beginning of this article.
We can show this by using the closed graph theorem for set-valued functions, which says that for a compact Hausdorff range space Y, a set-valued function φ: X→2Y has a closed graph if and only if it is upper hemicontinuous and φ is a closed set for all x. Since all Euclidean spaces are Hausdorff and φ is required to be closed-valued in the alternative statement of the Kakutani theorem, the Closed Graph Theorem implies that the two statements are equivalent.
Applications
Game theory
The Kakutani fixed point theorem can be used to prove the minimax theorem in the theory of zero-sum games. This application was specifically discussed by Kakutani's original paper.Mathematician John Nash used the Kakutani fixed point theorem to prove a major result in game theory. Stated informally, the theorem implies the existence of a Nash equilibrium in every finite game with mixed strategies for any number of players. This work later earned him a Nobel Prize in Economics. In this case:
- The base set S is the set of tuples of mixed strategies chosen by each player in a game. If each player has k possible actions, then each player's strategy is a k-tuple of probabilities summing up to 1, so each player's strategy space is the standard simplex in Rk. Then, S is the cartesian product of all these simplices. It is indeed a nonempty, compact and convex subset of Rkn.
- The function φ associates with each tuple a new tuple where each player's strategy is her best response to other players' strategies in x. Since there may be a number of responses which are equally good, φ is set-valued rather than single-valued. For each x, φ is nonempty since there is always at least one best response. It is convex, since a mixture of two best-responses for a player is still a best-response for the player. It can be proved that φ has a closed graph.
- Then the Nash equilibrium of the game is defined as a fixed point of φ, i.e. a tuple of strategies where each player's strategy is a best response to the strategies of the other players. Kakutani's theorem ensures that this fixed point exists.
General equilibrium
In this case:
- The base set S is the set of tuples of commodity prices.
- The function φ is chosen so that its result differs from its arguments as long as the price-tuple x does not equate supply and demand everywhere. The challenge here is to construct φ so that it has this property while at the same time satisfying the conditions in Kakutani's theorem. If this can be done then φ has a fixed point according to the theorem. Given the way it was constructed, this fixed point must correspond to a price-tuple which equates supply with demand everywhere.
Fair division
Proof outline
''S'' = 0,1
The proof of Kakutani's theorem is simplest for set-valued functions defined over closed intervals of the real line. However, the proof of this case is instructive since its general strategy can be carried over to the higher-dimensional case as well.Let φ:
Let for i = 0, 1, … be a sequence with the following properties:
Thus, the closed intervals
Such a sequence can be constructed as follows. Let a0 = 0 and b0 = 1. Let p0 be any point in φ and q0 be any point in φ. Then, conditions – are immediately fulfilled. Moreover, since p0 ∈ φ ⊂
Now suppose we have chosen ak, bk, pk and qk satisfying –. Let,
Then m ∈
If there is a r ∈ φ such that r ≥ m, then we take,
Otherwise, since φ is non-empty, there must be a s ∈ φ such that s ≤ m. In this case let,
It can be verified that ak+1, bk+1, pk+1 and qk+1 satisfy conditions –.
- Find a limiting point of the subdivisions.
But since ≤ 2−i by condition,
So, b* equals a*. Let x = b* = a*.
Then we have the situation that
- Show that the limiting point is a fixed point.
Otherwise, we can write the following. Recall that we can parameterize a line between two points a and b by a + tb. Using our finding above that q
it once again follows that x must belong to φ since p* and q* do and hence x is a fixed point of φ.
''S'' is a ''n''-simplex
In dimensions greater one, n-simplices are the simplest objects on which Kakutani's theorem can be proved. Informally, a n-simplex is the higher-dimensional version of a triangle. Proving Kakutani's theorem for set-valued function defined on a simplex is not essentially different from proving it for intervals. The additional complexity in the higher-dimensional case exists in the first step of chopping up the domain into finer subpieces:- Where we split intervals into two at the middle in the one-dimensional case, barycentric subdivision is used to break up a simplex into smaller sub-simplices.
- While in the one-dimensional case we could use elementary arguments to pick one of the half-intervals in a way that its end-points were moved in opposite directions, in the case of simplices the combinatorial result known as Sperner's lemma is used to guarantee the existence of an appropriate subsimplex.
Arbitrary ''S''
Kakutani's theorem for n-simplices can be used to prove the theorem for an arbitrary compact, convex S. Once again we employ the same technique of creating increasingly finer subdivisions. But instead of triangles with straight edges as in the case of n-simplices, we now use triangles with curved edges. In formal terms, we find a simplex which covers S and then move the problem from S to the simplex by using a deformation retract. Then we can apply the already established result for n-simplices.Infinite-dimensional generalizations
Kakutani's fixed-point theorem was extended to infinite-dimensional locally convex topological vector spaces by Irving Glicksbergand Ky Fan.
To state the theorem in this case, we need a few more definitions:
;Upper hemicontinuity: A set-valued function φ: X→2Y is upper hemicontinuous if for every open set W ⊂ Y, the set is open in X.
;Kakutani map: Let X and Y be topological vector spaces and φ: X→2Y be a set-valued function. If Y is convex, then φ is termed a Kakutani map if it is upper hemicontinuous and φ is non-empty, compact and convex for all x ∈ X.
Then the Kakutani–Glicksberg–Fan theorem can be stated as:
The corresponding result for single-valued functions is the Tychonoff fixed-point theorem.
There is another version that the statement of the theorem becomes the same as that in the Euclidean case: