Ranked voting


Ranked voting is any election voting system in which voters use a ranked ballot to rank choices in a sequence on the ordinal scale: 1st, 2nd, 3rd, etc. There are multiple ways in which the rankings can be counted to determine which candidate is elected. The other major branch of voting systems is cardinal voting, where candidates are independently rated, rather than ranked.
The similar term "Ranked Choice Voting" is used by the US organization FairVote to refer to the use of ranked ballots with specific counting methods: either instant-runoff voting for single-winner elections or single transferable vote for multi-winner elections. In some locations, the term "preferential voting" is used to refer to this combination of ballot type and counting method, while in other locations this term has various more-specialized meanings.
A ranked voting system collects more information from voters compared to the single-mark ballots currently used in most governmental elections, many of which use First-Past-The-Post and Mixed-Member Proportional voting systems.
There are many types of ranked voting, with several used in governmental elections. Instant-runoff voting is used in Australian state and federal elections, in Ireland for its presidential elections, and by some jurisdictions in the United States, United Kingdom, and New Zealand. A type and classification of ranked voting is called the single transferable vote, which is used for national elections in Ireland and Malta, the Australian Senate, for regional and local elections in Northern Ireland, for all local elections in Scotland, and for some local elections in New Zealand and the United States. Borda count is used in Slovenia and Nauru. Contingent vote and Supplementary vote are also used in a few locations. Condorcet methods are used by private organizations and minor parties, but currently are not used in governmental elections.
Arrow's impossibility theorem and Gibbard's theorem prove that all voting systems must make trade-offs between desirable properties, such as the preference between two candidates being unaffected by the popularity of a third candidate. Accordingly there is no consensus among academics or public servants as to the "best" electoral system.
Recently, an increasing number of authors, including David Farrell, Ian McAllister and Jurij Toplak, see preferentiality as one of the characteristics by which electoral systems can be evaluated. According to this view, all electoral methods are preferential, but to different degrees and may even be classified according to their preferentiality. By this logic, cardinal voting methods such as Score voting or STAR voting are also "preferential".

Types

There are different preferential voting systems, so it is sometimes difficult to distinguish between them.
Selection of the Condorcet winner is generally considered by psephologists as the ideal election outcome for a ranked system, so "Condorcet efficiency" is important when evaluating different methods of preferential voting. The Condorcet winner is the one that would win every two-way contest against every other alternative.
Another criterion used to gauge the effectiveness of a preferential voting system is its ability to withstand manipulative voting strategies, when voters cast ballots that do not reflect their preferences in the hope of electing their first choice. This can be rated on at least two dimensions—the number of voters needed to game the system, and the sophistication of the strategy necessary.

Instant-runoff voting

Used in national elections in Australia, this system is said to simulate a series of runoff elections. If no candidate is the first choice of more than half of the voters, then all votes cast for the candidate with the lowest number of first choices are redistributed to the remaining candidates based on who is ranked next on each ballot. If this does not result in any candidate receiving a majority, further rounds of redistribution occur.
This method is thought to be resistant to manipulative voting as the only strategies that work against it require voters to highly rank choices they actually want to see lose. At the same time, this system fails Condorcet criterion, meaning a candidate can win even if the voters preferred a different candidate, and fails the monotonicity criterion, where ranking a candidate higher can lessen the chances he or she will be elected and vice versa. Additionally, instant-runoff voting has a lower Condorcet efficiency than similar systems when there are more than four choices.

Single transferable vote

This is one of the preferential voting systems most used by countries and states. It is used for electing multi-member constituencies. Any candidates that achieve the number of votes required for election are elected and their surplus votes are redistributed to the voter's next choice candidate. Once this is done, if not all places have been filled then the candidate with the lowest number of votes is eliminated, and their votes are also redistributed to the voter's next choice. This whole process is repeated until all seats are filled. This method is also called the Hare-Clark system.
When single transferable vote is used for single-winner elections, it becomes equivalent to instant-runoff voting.

Condorcet method

Positional voting

Positional voting is a ranked voting electoral system in which the options receive points based on their rank position on each ballot and the option with the most points overall wins.

Borda count

Borda is a positional system in which ballots are counted by assigning a point value to each place in each voter's ranking of the candidates, and the choice with the largest number of points overall is elected. This method is named after its inventor, French mathematician Jean-Charles de Borda. Instead of selecting a Condorcet winner, this system may select a choice that reflects an average of the preferences of the constituency.
The Borda count does not exhibit independence of irrelevant alternatives or independence of clones meaning the outcome it selects is dependent on the other choices present. In large scale elections, the Borda Count is only weakly manipulated by adding candidates, called clones, whose views are similar to the preferred candidate's, but in a small committee election it can more easily manipulated. An example of this strategy can be seen in Kiribati's 1991 presidential nomination contest.

Path Voting (Schulze Method)

Uniqueness of votes

If there are a large number of candidates, which is quite common in single transferable vote elections, then it is likely that many preference voting patterns will be unique to individual voters. For example, in the 2002 Irish general election, the electronic votes were published for the Dublin North constituency. There were 12 candidates and almost 44,000 votes cast. The most common pattern was chosen by only 800 voters, and more than 16,000 patterns were chosen by just one voter each.
The number of possible complete rankings with no ties is the factorial of the number of candidates, N; but if ties are allowed freely, it is equal to the corresponding ordered Bell number and is asymptotic to
In the case common to instant-runoff voting in which no ties are allowed, except for unranked candidates who are tied for last place on a ballot, the number of possible rankings for N candidates is precisely

Use by politics

Countries and regions

CountryYears in useTypeNotes
Australia1918–presentSingle transferable vote, instant-runoff votingFrom 1949, the single transferable vote method has been used for upper house legislative elections. Instant-runoff voting is used for lower house elections.
CanadaInstant-runoff votingUsed in whole or in part to elect the leaders of the three largest federal political parties in Canada: the Liberal Party of Canada, the Conservative Party of Canada, and the New Democratic Party, albeit the New Democratic Party uses a mixture of IRV and exhaustive voting, allowing each member to choose one format or the other for their vote.
Estonia1990–Single transferable voteAs of 2001, single transferable vote had been in use since 1990 to decide legislative elections. This is no longer the case.
Fiji1998–presentInstant-runoff voting
Hong Kong1998–presentInstant-runoff votingInstant-runoff voting is only used in the 4 smallest of Hong Kong's 29 functional constituencies. Officially called preferential elimination voting, the system is identical to the instant-runoff voting.
Ireland1922–presentInstant-runoff voting, single transferable voteSingle transferable vote is used to decide legislative elections only. Since 1937 Ireland has used instant-runoff voting to decide presidential elections.
Malta1921–presentSingle transferable vote
Nauru1968–presentBorda countNauru uses the Dowdall system, a variant of the Borda count that behaves more like FPTP.
New Zealand2004–presentSingle transferable voteInstant-runoff voting is used in only some single-seat elections, such as district health boards as well as some city and district councils.
Northern Ireland1973–presentSingle transferable voteUsed for local government, European Parliament and the regional legislature, but not elections to Westminster.
Papua New Guinea2007–presentInstant-runoff votingBetween 1964 and 1975, Papua New Guinea used a system that allowed voters the option of ranking candidates. Currently, voters can rank only their top three choices.
Slovenia2000–presentBorda countOnly two seats, which are reserved for Hungarian and Italian minorities, are decided using a Borda count.
Sri Lanka1978–presentContingent vote and open listContingent vote is used for presidential elections, and open list for legislative elections.
United States2020Limited instant-runoff votingIn their 2020 primaries, the Democratic Party permitted voters who could not be physically present at the Iowa and Nevada caucus to early vote using a preferential ballot.
Zimbabwe1979–1985Instant-runoff votingWas only used for white candidates

Federal provinces or states

Province/stateCountryYears in useTypeNotes
AlbertaCanada1952–1954Instant-runoff voting
Australian Capital TerritoryAustralia1993–presentSingle transferable vote
British ColumbiaCanada1926–1955Instant-runoff voting
MaineUnited States2018–presentInstant-runoff voting Originally approved by Maine voters as a 2016 ballot referendum to replace the First Past The Post system statewide, a 2017 state law sought to delay implementation of ranked-choice voting until 2021, to allow time for amending the state constitution. Supporters overrode the delay with a 2018 people's veto referendum that received a majority of votes, ensuring that ranked-choice voting would be used for future primary and federal elections.
ManitobaCanada1927–1936Instant-runoff voting
New South WalesAustralia1918–presentSingle transferable vote, contingent vote, instant-runoff voting Since 1978, NSW has used the single transferable vote method to decide upper house legislative elections only. Full preferential voting for lower house since 1981.
North CarolinaUnited States2006–2013Instant-runoff votingA state law in 2006 established instant-runoff voting for certain judicial elections, until a 2013 law repealed the practice.
Northern TerritoryAustralia1980 only
OntarioCanada2018–presentInstant-runoff voting In 2016, the provincial government passed Bill 181, the Municipal Elections Modernization Act, which permitted municipalities to adopt ranked balloting in municipal elections. In the 2018 elections, the first ones conducted under the new legislation, the city of London used ranked balloting, while the cities of Kingston and Cambridge held referendums on whether to adopt ranked ballots for the next municipal elections in 2022.
QueenslandAustralia1892–1942, 1962–presentContingent vote, instant-runoff voting Full preferential voting used 1962–1992 and since 2016.
South AustraliaAustralia1929–present, 1982–presentInstant-runoff voting, single transferable vote Instant runoff for the lower house, single transferable for the upper house.
TasmaniaAustralia1907–presentSingle transferable vote, instant-runoff voting Single transferable for the lower house, instant runoff for the upper house.
VictoriaAustralia1911–presentInstant-runoff voting, single transferable vote Prior to 1916, Victoria did not use any preferential voting method to decide upper house legislative elections. Instant runoff for the lower house, single transferable for the upper house. Full preferential voting for lower house since 1916.
Western AustraliaAustralia1907–presentInstant-runoff voting, single transferable vote Instant runoff for the lower house, single transferable for the upper house. Full preferential voting for lower house since 1912.

Municipalities

City/townYears in useTypeNotes
Ann Arbor, MI1975 onlyInstant-runoff voting
Aspen, CO2009 onlyInstant-runoff voting
Berkeley, CA2010–presentInstant-runoff voting
Burlington, VT2005–2010Instant-runoff votingended after the Burlington mayoral election of 2009
Cambridge, MA1941–presentSingle transferable vote
Hendersonville, NC2007–2013Instant-runoff votingpart of a statewide pilot program, deauthorized in 2013
London2000–presentSupplementary vote
London, Ontario2018 – presentInstant-runoff voting
Memphis, TN2011–presentInstant-runoff voting
Minneapolis, MN2009–presentInstant-runoff voting
Oakland, CA2010–presentInstant-runoff voting
Portland, ME2011–presentInstant-runoff voting
San Francisco, CA2004–presentInstant-runoff voting
San Leandro, CA2010–presentInstant-runoff voting
Santa Fe, NM2018–presentInstant-runoff voting
St. Paul, MN2011–presentInstant-runoff voting
Takoma Park, MD2006–presentInstant-runoff voting
Telluride, CO2011–presentInstant-runoff voting

International organizations

OrganizationYears in useTypeNotes
European Unionoption to use single transferable voteMember countries can use either proportional representation or single transferable vote to elect MEPs

Use outside of politics

The winner of the Eurovision Song Contest is selected by a positional voting system. The most recent system was implemented in the 2016 contest, and sees each participating country award two sets of 12, 10, 8–1 points to their 10 favourite songs: one set from their professional jury and the other from tele-voting.