Continuous game


A continuous game is a mathematical concept, used in game theory, that generalizes the idea of an ordinary game like tic-tac-toe or checkers. In other words, it extends the notion of a discrete game, where the players choose from a finite set of pure strategies. The continuous game concepts allows games to include more general sets of pure strategies, which may be uncountably infinite.
In general, a game with uncountably infinite strategy sets will not necessarily have a Nash equilibrium solution. If, however, the strategy sets are required to be compact and the utility functions continuous, then a Nash equilibrium will be guaranteed; this is by Glicksberg's generalization of the Kakutani fixed point theorem. The class of continuous games is for this reason usually defined and studied as a subset of the larger class of infinite games in which the strategy sets are compact and the utility functions continuous.

Formal definition

Define the n-player continuous game where
Let be a strategy profile of all players except for player. As with discrete games, we can define a best response for player,. is a relation from the set of all probability distributions over opponent player profiles to a set of player 's strategies, such that each element of
is a best response to. Define
A strategy profile is a Nash equilibrium if and only if
The existence of a Nash equilibrium for any continuous game with continuous utility functions can be proven using Irving Glicksberg's generalization of the Kakutani fixed point theorem. In general, there may not be a solution if we allow strategy spaces, 's which are not compact, or if we allow non-continuous utility functions.

Separable games

A separable game is a continuous game where, for any i, the utility function can be expressed in the sum-of-products form:
A polynomial game is a separable game where each is a compact interval on and each utility function can be written as a multivariate polynomial.
In general, mixed Nash equilibria of separable games are easier to compute than non-separable games as implied by the following theorem:
Whereas an equilibrium strategy for a non-separable game may require an uncountably infinite support, a separable game is guaranteed to have at least one Nash equilibrium with finitely supported mixed strategies.

Examples

Separable games

A polynomial game

Consider a zero-sum 2-player game between players X and Y, with. Denote elements of and as and respectively. Define the utility functions where
The pure strategy best response relations are:
and do not intersect, so there is
no pure strategy Nash equilibrium.
However, there should be a mixed strategy equilibrium. To find it, express the expected value, as a linear combination of the first and second moments of the probability distributions of X and Y:
.
The constraints on and are given by Hausdorff as:
Each pair of constraints defines a compact convex subset in the plane. Since is linear, any extrema with respect to a player's first two moments will lie on the boundary of this subset. Player i's equilibrium strategy will lie on
Note that the first equation only permits mixtures of 0 and 1 whereas the second equation only permits pure strategies. Moreover, if the best response at a certain point to player i lies on, it will lie on the whole line, so that both 0 and 1 are a best response. simply gives the pure strategy, so will never give both 0 and 1.
However gives both 0 and 1 when y = 1/2.
A Nash equilibrium exists when:
This determines one unique equilibrium where Player X plays a random mixture of 0 for 1/2 of the time and 1 the other 1/2 of the time. Player Y plays the pure strategy of 1/2. The value of the game is 1/4.

Non-Separable Games

A rational pay-off function

Consider a zero-sum 2-player game between players X and Y, with. Denote elements of and as and respectively. Define the utility functions where
This game has no pure strategy Nash equilibrium. It can be shown that a unique mixed strategy Nash equilibrium exists with the following pair of probability density functions:
The value of the game is.

Requiring a Cantor distribution

Consider a zero-sum 2-player game between players X and Y, with. Denote elements of and as and respectively. Define the utility functions where
This game has a unique mixed strategy equilibrium where each player plays a mixed strategy with the cantor singular function as the cumulative distribution function.