Envy-free item allocation
Envy-free item allocation is a fair item allocation problem, in which the fairness criterion is envy-freeness - each agent should receive a bundle that he believes to be at least as good as the bundle of any other agent.
Since the items are indivisible, an EF assignment may not exist. The simplest case is when there is a single item and at least two agents: if the item is assigned to one agent, the other will envy. Therefore, the division procedures provide various kinds of relaxations.
Finding an envy-free allocation whenever it exists
Preference-orderings on bundles: envy-freeness
The undercut procedure finds a complete EF allocation for two agents, if-and-only-if such allocation exists. It requires the agents to rank bundles of items, but it does not require cardinal utility information. It works whenever the agents' preference relations are strictly monotone, but does not need to assume that they are responsive preferences. In the worst case, the agents may have to rank all possible bundles, so the run-time might be exponential in the number of items.Preference-orderings on items: necessary/possible envy-freeness
It is usually easier for people to rank individual items than to rank bundles. Assuming all agents have responsive preferences, it is possible to lift the item-ranking to a partial bundle-ranking. For example, if the item-ranking is w>x>y>z, then responsiveness implies that > and >, but does not imply anything about the relation between and, between and, etc.Given an item-ranking:
- An allocation is necessarily envy-free if it is envy-free according to all responsive bundle-rankings consistent with the item-ranking;
- An allocation is possibly envy-free if it is envy-free according to at least one responsive bundle-ranking consistent with the item-ranking;
- An allocation is necessarily Pareto-optimal if it is Pareto-optimal according to all responsive bundle-rankings consistent with the item-ranking;
- An allocation is possibly Pareto-optimal if it is Pareto-optimal according to at least one responsive bundle-ranking consistent with the item-ranking.
Deciding whether an EF allocation exists
The empty allocation is always EF. But if we want some efficiency in addition to EF, then the decision problem becomes computationally hard:- Deciding whether an EF and complete allocation exists is NP complete. This is true even when there are only two agents, and even when their utilities are additive and identical, since in this case finding an EF allocation is equivalent to solving the partition problem.
- Deciding whether an EF and Pareto efficient allocation exists is above NP: it is -complete even with dichotomous preferences and even with additive utilities.
Finding an allocation with a bounded level of envy
Round-robin procedure
When all agents have weakly additive utilities, the following protocol attains a complete EF1 allocation:- Order the agents arbitrarily.
- While there are unassigned items:
- * Let each agent from 1 to pick an item.
Envy-cycles procedure
The envy-cycles procedure returns a complete EF1 allocation for arbitrary preference relations. The only requirement is that the agents can rank bundles of items.If the agents' valuations are represented by a cardinal utility function, then the EF1 guarantee has an additional interpretation: the numeric envy-level of each agent is at most the maximal-marginal-utility - the largest marginal utility of a single item for that agent.
Approximate-CEEI procedure
The A-CEEI mechanism returns a partial EF1 allocation for arbitrary preference relations. The only requirement is that the agents can rank bundles of items.A small number of items might remain unallocated; the allocation is Pareto-efficient with respect to the allocated items. Moreover, the A-CEEI mechanism is approximately strategyproof when the number of agents is large.
Maximum-Nash-Welfare
The Maximum-Nash-Welfare algorithm selects a complete allocation that maximizes the product of utilities. It requires each agent to provide a numeric valuation of each item, and assumes that the agents' utilities are additive. The resulting allocation is both EF1 and Pareto-efficient.If the agents' utilities are not additive, the MNW solution is not necessarily EF1; but if the agents' utilities are at least submodular, the MNW solution satisfies a weaker property called Marginal-Envy-Freeness except-1-item.
EF1 vs EFx
There is an alternative criterion called Envy-freeness-except-cheapest : For each two agents A and B, if we remove from the bundle of B any item, then A does not envy B. EFx is strictly stronger than EF1. As of this writing, it is not known whether EFx allocations always exist.Minimizing the envy-ratio
Given an allocation X, define the envy ratio of i in j as:so the ratio is 1 if i does not envy j, and it is larger when i envies j.
Define the envy ratio of an assignment as:
The envy ratio minimization problem is the problem of finding an allocation X with smallest envy ratio.
General valuations
With general valuations, any deterministic algorithm that computes an alloсation with minimum envy-ratio requires a number of queries which is exponential in the number of goods in the worst case.Additive and identical valuations
With additive and identical valuations:- The following greedy algorithm finds an allocation whose envy-ratio is at most 1.4 times the minimum:
- # Order the items by descending value;
- # While there are more items, give the next item to an agent with the smallest total value.
- There is a PTAS for envy-ratio minimization. Furthermore, when the number of players is constant, there is an FPTAS.
Additive and different valuations
- When the number of agents is part of the input, it is impossible to obtain in polynomial time an approximation factor better than 1.5, unless P=NP.
- When the number of agents is constant, there is an FPTAS.
- When the number of agents equals the number of items, there is a polynomial-time algorithm.
Finding a partial envy-free allocation
The Adjusted winner procedure returns a complete and efficient EF allocation for two agents, but it might have to cut a single item. It requires the agents to report a numeric value for each item, and assumes that they have additive utilities
Existence of EF allocations with random valuations
If the agents have additive utility functions that are drawn from probability distributions satisfying some independence criteria, and the number of items is sufficiently large relative to the number of agents, then an EF allocation exists with high probability. Particularly:- If the number of items is sufficiently large:, then w.h.p. an EF allocation exists.
- If the number of items is not sufficiently large, i.e.,, then w.h.p. an EF allocation does not exist.
Envy-freeness vs. other fairness criteria
- Every EF allocation is min-max-fair. This follows directly from the ordinal definitions and does not depend on additivity.
- If all agents have additive utility functions, then an EF allocation is also proportional and max-min-fair. Otherwise, an EF allocation may be not proportional and even not max-min-fair.
- Every allocation of a competitive equilibrium from equal incomes is also envy-free. This is true regardless of additivity.
- Every Nash-optimal allocation is EF1.
Summary table
Below, the following shorthands are used:- = the number of agents participating in the division;
- = the number of items to divide;
- EF = envy-free, EF1 = envy-free except-1-item, MEF1 = marginal-envy-free except-1-item.
- PE = Pareto-efficient.
Name | #partners | Input | Preferences | #queries | Fairness | Efficiency | Comments |
Undercut | 2 | Bundle ranking | Strictly monotone | EF | Complete | If-and-only-if a complete EF allocation exists | |
AL | 2 | Item ranking | Weakly additive | Necessarily-EF | Partial, but not Pareto-dominated by another NEF | ||
Adjusted winner | 2 | Item valuations | Additive | EF and equitable | PE | Might divide one item. | |
Round-robin | Item ranking | Weakly additive | Necessarily-EF1 | Complete | |||
Envy-cycles | Bundle ranking | Monotone | EF1 | Complete | |||
A-CEEI | Bundle ranking | Any | ? | EF1, and -maximin-share | Partial, but PE w.r.t. allocated items | Also approximately strategyproof when there are many agents. | |
Maximum-Nash-Welfare | Item valuations | Additive | NP-hard | EF1, and approximately--maximin-share | PE | With submodular utilities, allocation is PE and MEF1. |